Resources | Subject Notes | Economics
The demand for labour is not autonomous; it is a derived demand. This means that the demand for labour is ultimately derived from the demand for the goods and services that labour helps to produce. In simpler terms, businesses hire workers because they need to produce goods or services that consumers want to buy.
The fundamental principle of derived demand is that the demand for a resource (in this case, labour) is linked to the demand for the final product it helps create. If the demand for the final product falls, the demand for the labour required to produce it will also fall.
Consider a scenario: if consumer demand for smartphones decreases, phone manufacturers will produce fewer smartphones. This reduced production will lead to a lower need for workers in the manufacturing process, resulting in a decrease in the demand for labour in the smartphone industry.
The labour demand curve typically slopes downwards, reflecting the inverse relationship between the wage rate and the quantity of labour demanded. This is because as wages rise, firms are less willing to hire workers, and as wages fall, firms are more willing to hire workers.
The shape of the labour demand curve is influenced by several factors:
The intersection of the labour demand curve and the labour supply curve determines the equilibrium wage rate and the equilibrium quantity of labour employed.
Factor | Effect on Demand for Labour |
---|---|
Price of Output | Directly Proportional |
Price of Capital | Inversely Proportional |
Productivity of Labour | Directly Proportional |
Number of Firms | Directly Proportional |
Governments often intervene in the labour market to address perceived market failures, such as unemployment, inequality, and wage suppression. Common forms of government intervention include:
The impact of government interventions can be complex and often leads to unintended consequences. For example, a minimum wage might lead to job losses if the mandated wage is set above the market-clearing wage.